Pensions are a
complicated business, and the UK State Pension is particularly so, given that
the rules, amounts and eligibility criteria for the different rates keep
changing. But in looking at the history of the triple lock, we need to go back
to the Thatcher years. For some years prior to 1980, the uprating of pensions
was based on a combination of average earnings and the Retail Price Index, but
Thatcher’s legislation in 1980 ended the link with average earnings. Over the
long term (even if it doesn’t always feel that way!), wages tend to rise faster than
prices, which is why people generally feel better off over time and enjoy a
rising standard of living. But an income linked only to prices will inevitably do
no more than maintain a standard of living, and the extent to which it even
does that will depend on which prices are included in the calculation and the
extent to which the things purchased by an individual match that selected ‘basket’.
Those on lower incomes (such as those dependent on the state pension) often
find that their more personal rate of inflation is higher than the overall
average, meaning that they slip backwards.
The triple lock was
intended to reverse that decline and bring the state pension back to the
effective relationship it had with earnings prior to 1980. On that basis, Steve
Webb (the Minister who introduced the policy) was surely right when he said recently that "there
will come a point when it's done its job". Whether merely ‘restoring’
that relationship to its pre-Thatcher level is the right target or not is a
matter of opinion; there has been remarkably little debate about what the ‘right’
relationship between earnings and pensions should be. 30%? 50%? 80%? 100%? Parking
that issue, the question in considering whether the triple lock has done its
job or not should be an assessment of whether the percentage is or is not back
to the 1980 level. At that point, and assuming some sort of agreement on the ‘right’
percentage of average earnings, a single lock (with average earnings) is all
that is needed, and would also align the incomes of pensioners and employed
people in the same relationship with price inflation. But making that
assessment isn’t straightforward because of other changes to pensions (including
the move from the old married couple pension to individual pensions, for
example), but if any of those arguing for the abolition of the triple lock
truly felt that they could make a good case for having restored the 1980 value
of pensions, we can be certain that they’d be shouting it from the rooftops.
The rooftops are looking and sounding conspicuously quiet.
They don’t, of course, put it in these terms, but anyone arguing for abolition of the triple lock (and Labour seems to have its share of them as well as the Tories) is effectively arguing for an arrangement which, at best, locks the rate of pensions at its existing relationship with average earnings. It’s easy enough to see why they avoid putting it that way – it’s not an argument that I’d want to make given the comparatively low level of the UK state pension. Those arguing that better off pensioners (those with savings and investments or good occupational or private pensions) don’t ‘need’ the full state pension and should be paid a lower amount are being disingenuous at best, and avoiding the real point at worst. Pensions, of necessity, require long term decision-making, and many people will have planned for their retirement on the basis of assuming that the ‘deal’ that they thought they were getting when they started work – paying NI in return for pensions in later life – would be honoured in due course. Had they known in advance that that particular income source would then be means-tested, they may well have taken different decisions, but they can’t go back and do something different. There is another way, though. Those on higher incomes – whether through pensions, interest payments, dividends, rents or wages – could be asked to pay more in tax. The source of that income ought to be irrelevant: the clue is in the name, it’s an income tax. The talk about reducing the state pension for some recipients is really about avoiding that issue. Labour, just like the Tories, is reluctant to tax more heavily those who can best afford to pay it. Talk of ‘need’ or ‘means tests’ is just a distraction from that reluctance to in any way reduce the disposable income of the group in society which they represent and serve - the most well-off.
No comments:
Post a Comment