Thursday, 2 October 2025

Where's the ideological response to Tory nonsense?

Accusing the ‘Welsh’ Tories of possessing principles of any sort would be a foul calumny, but lacking any basic principles isn’t the same as lacking certain fundamental ideological beliefs. One of those is that tax cuts are axiomatically a good thing, and they are at it again today in the Senedd, calling for a cut in income tax and the abolition of business rates for small businesses. These changes, they claim, will put more money in peoples’ pockets and boost economic growth.

The Welsh government (and the Welsh budget) are fundamentally different creatures from the UK versions, and don’t have the same freedoms. It’s a consequence of the difference between devolution and independence: an independent government in control of its own currency and with debt mostly denominated in that currency can spend as much as it wants to as long as the physical resources are available, and that spending isn’t constrained by the availability of money through taxation. The Welsh government has no such freedom: it’s budget, and its ability to borrow or transfer money between financial years are limited by external dictat, and over a period, it must balance the books. It means, in essence, that whilst it’s not true that a UK tax cut must be balanced by spending cuts, it is very definitely the case that a Welsh tax cut must be balanced by spending cuts. And the Tories know it, even if they didn’t spell it out.

What that translates to in practice is that, whilst the tax cuts proposed by the Tories may make individuals and small businesses feel better off initially, they will either have fewer (or worse) services delivered by the Welsh government (and by the local authorities who receive large transfers from the government in Cardiff), or find that they have to pay more for the same services out of the ‘extra’ money they gained from the tax cuts. More people will end up paying for private health care, or private tuition, for example. There will be those who argue that that is a ‘good’ thing, and that those services can be provided better or more cheaply by private providers. Whether that is true or not (and I’m not at all convinced by the arguments) is irrelevant to the economics here – a subject for another day. The point is that those who gain most from the tax cuts will be better able to afford such things than those who gain least – and that is especially so for those who earn so little that they pay little or no income tax already.

Whenever a tax cut is proposed which leads to cuts in what the government can do, it necessarily promotes a further disparity between those who can afford to bridge some or all of the gap and those who cannot. Some won’t be able to do so at all and will suffer as a result; others will see all the gains from their tax cuts swallowed up by extra costs; and the luckiest few will end up banking the difference. It goes to the heart of the argument for funding some basic services in society collectively, through taxation and public bodies, as opposed to leaving individuals to find the money to pay themselves or go without. Concentrating primarily on the financial effect on the Welsh government and its budget – which seems to be Labour’s response – is to miss the underlying ideological point. For too long, the argument about collective provision rather than individual provision has gone largely unmade, an omission from the debate which helps only the Tories.


Wednesday, 1 October 2025

Reeves is sidestepping the real question

 

One of the neat rhetorical tricks used by politicians is to present an inaccurate view of what their opponents say and show how easy it is to dismiss. It helps them ‘score a point’ as well as allowing them to fail to engage with the underlying argument. The Chancellor, Rachel Reeves, was at it this week, refuting the suggestion that governments can simply create all the money that they need and then spend it. She’s right in principle; but I’m not aware that anyone has actually made the argument that she dismissed. Of course there are constraints on how much government can spend, but the debate is about what those constraints are, not whether or not they exist.

She argues that the constraints are twofold, which are closely interlinked: the amount of money which the government receives through taxes etc. and the need to abide by the fiscal rules she has laid down. But, in the first place, the rules she has laid down are entirely arbitrary. She has set them, and she could remove them or vary them. The UK never had any fiscal rules at all until Labour introduced them in 1997, and they have been changed regularly ever since, usually when a new Chancellor takes office, and sometimes during the period of tenure of a single chancellor. And a government which controls its own currency, and whose debt is mostly denominated in that currency, can create as much money as it wants to, any time it chooses, and can always repay any debts it incurs. Since money is merely a means of measuring and trading debt, and all debt has to be matched by an asset somewhere, the total net debt in an economy, in its simplest form, is always zero. It’s an over-simplification, yes, but it doesn’t matter how much extra money the government creates, the total net debt in the economy will always be zero. It cannot be otherwise. There is a non-trivial issue, of course, about how that debt and those assets are distributed, but that’s another issue which the chancellor seems wholly unwilling to address, and it doesn’t affect the simple fact that money creation is potentially unlimited.

That doesn’t mean that there are no constraints on the goverment, just that ‘money’ isn’t one of them. The real constraint on money creation and spending is the availability of real resources in the economy. If there are unused resources which could be put to work, the money to do that can be created. If there aren’t then the most basic rules of economics apply – more money competing for the same resources causes inflation. The question which we should be asking is not whether the government can create and spend money to improve services and improve living standards, but whether and to what extent the resources needed to do those things are available in the economy. It’s not an easy question to answer. As one example of the impact of government spending, increasing benefits (by, for instance, scrapping the two child cap) puts more money into the economy which will then be spent, potentially driving employment - in this case, largely in the retail sector. Roughly 4.7% of the working age population in the UK are currently unemployed, but how many of them are really available and suitable for the right work in the right places when the government spends more money, before generating demand no longer soaks up unused human resources but starts to compete for existing employed resources? The best answer that can be given without a lot of work is ‘some, but not all’.

But being a difficult question to answer is no excuse for not asking it and trying to find an answer; hiding behind her own rules and an alleged lack of money is just a very lame excuse for avoiding the question.

Tuesday, 30 September 2025

Starmer is avoiding honestly facing the problem of racism

 

At the weekend, Starmer told us that he didn’t think Reform Ltd voters were racists, merely frustrated. It’s a sweeping statement to make. Although it’s entirely reasonable to suppose that some Reform Ltd voters are not racists, it doesn’t follow that none of them are. It also doesn’t address the converse: whilst it may well be true that voting for Farage’s lot doesn’t make someone a racist, it doesn’t follow at all that being racists doesn’t drive people to vote for Reform Ltd. Whilst it’s not an absolute, 100% causal link, it’s not a bad indicator. Racists have a strong tendency to think that Farage is expressing their views, and not without justification.

When asked directly whether Reform Ltd were trying to appeal to racists, Starmer’s response was a flat “No”, before proceeding to waffle about frustration and economic decline. Given that he’d already said that he thought that Reform Ltd policies were racist, this is a somewhat astonishing contradiction. What on earth is the point in promising outright racist policies if not to appeal to racists? His problem is that – just like Farage and Badenoch – he too is trying to appeal to racists. Not only to racists, of course; and maybe not so blatantly as Farage, but in a sense, that just makes it worse. Offering skimmed or semi-skimmed racism legitimises the full fat version, and can make voting for the real thing more acceptable.

Pretending that anger whipped up by the tabloids over migration is really just about the impact of economic decline and that people’s ‘concerns’ can be addressed by improving the NHS and putting more money in their pockets is wilfully turning a blind eye to the pernicious presence of racism. There is more racism, and even more latent racism, around than most of us would really like to acknowledge, even if racist voters don’t all choose to vote for Reform Ltd. It’s understandable that a PM tanking as badly in the polls as Starmer would be fearful of losing more votes to Farage, but aping his rhetoric in milder terms looks more like panic than a thought-through strategy. Whilst he might be more comfortable competing with other ‘right wing’ parties for the votes he’s losing in that direction, it seems as though he’s oblivious to those deserting Labour for the ‘left’, although there is evidence to suggest that he’d actually find it easier to get those back than those who’ve gone over to the Farageist dark side. It might be easier to pretend that it’s all about economics, but it isn’t honest.

Monday, 29 September 2025

Money spent by government doesn't generally simply disappear

 

One of the arguments against the Nation of Sanctuary policy which the Tories and Reform Ltd advance is that they want the money spent on the project diverted instead into local communities. The Reform Ltd candidate for the Caerffili by-election probably put it most clearly saying that we should “bring that money back to communities”, but the same point has been expressed in different words by others. It’s economically illiterate (or should that be innumerate?). Where do they think the money used for the project goes? It doesn’t simply pass from the government into a big black hole labelled ‘refugees’ pockets’; it gets spent. On accommodation, on food, on language lessons, on venues, on helping people to integrate and find work – and all that expenditure goes ‘back into the communities’. Much of the spending leads to payment of VAT, and the money which becomes other peoples’ income (as most of it does, eventually) leads to payment of Income Tax and National Insurance. It might not be a big project where the sponsors can put up a giant billboard declaring that it was funded by the Welsh Government, but the cash mostly ends up in local communities, circulating and providing income to people.

There’s a more general point there as well. The above doesn’t only relate to the Nation of Sanctuary. When the government pays out benefits and pensions, that money doesn’t just disappear either. It, too, gets spent in communities and ends up as income for other people, generating tax receipts as it does so. Looking at all government expenditure as though the money spent has gone and disappeared for ever is looking only at a single part of the flow of money: the economic effect of that expenditure is much wider. When it comes to this variety of economic innumeracy around benefits, Labour are as guilty as the Tories and Reform Ltd. There’s something else that we know for certain as well: the less well-off people are, the more likely it is that none of the money they receive will be saved, and all of it will be spent, mostly in the communities where they live.

Having said that, there is one important way in which spending by the government can make money disappear from our communities, and that is when it ends up in the pockets of the richest. As, for instance, when benefits are cut to enable tax cuts, something which always benefits those who pay most tax. Those who can afford to save often do. And money saved is money no longer circulating, no longer providing an income to someone else. Worse, some of those savings end up in offshore accounts – disappearing not only from local communities but from the whole country. Yet that, in effect, is the economic policy supported by Labour, Tory and Reform Ltd alike.

There is scope for debate about what the most effective method is for a government – any government – to put money into local communities. Is it through large, highly-visible projects which feed through into incomes, or is it by making sure more directly that all citizens – yes, and guests, whether temporary or permanent – have sufficient income and/or publicly-funded services to be able to meet their needs and live a decent life? Which approach has the greatest effect in the shortest timescale is a legitimate subject for debate. We should remember though that the two aren’t even mutually exclusive: the constraint on what we can do isn’t the availability of money, it’s the availability of resources, an economic truth which has been known for decades. Claiming that one way of spending money simply makes that money disappear is a dishonest way of avoiding that truth, while blaming the poorest for their own plight and facilitating the accumulation of wealth in fewer and fewer hands.

Saturday, 27 September 2025

Voters aren't fish, and don't always choose the 'right' angler

 

A couple of weeks ago, following a by-election in the Vale of Glamorgan, this blog post talked about the need to count, rather than assume, voters’ second choices. The question about making assumptions came up again on Thursday, in this article by Ben Wildsmith on Nation.Cymru, calling on Gareth Hughes and the Green Party to withdraw from the Caerffili by-election. I’m something of a fan of Ben’s writing: his articles are well-argued, make good points, and are often humorous to boot. But on this occasion, I cannot agree with his logic. The idea that parties seen as outside chances should ‘stand down’ to avoid ‘splitting the vote’ and letting (insert your bĂȘte noir of choice here) win is not one I’ve ever been keen on, although my view might be slightly coloured by having been on the receiving end of such expectations on more than one occasion.

There tends to be something of a belief amongst those performing mathematics on polling numbers that there are only two pools of voters. One contains only progressive fish, with Labour, Lib Dem, Plaid and Green anglers all trying to catch them, and the other contains only reactionary fish, with anglers from the Tories and Reform Ltd trying to haul them in. Since the number of fish in both ponds is limited, any caught by one angler are unavailable to the other anglers, and if one of those anglers is better at catching fish than the rest, his total catch is still limited by the number of fish caught by his competitors. And, obviously, the more anglers in one pond, the harder it is to match the catch of the best angler in the other. I’ve knocked enough doors and spoken to enough punters to know that life really isn’t that simple. Voters don’t always stay in their allotted pond, and if the Green angler lays down his rod, some of the fish are as likely to swim into the other pond as they are to leap onto the Plaid angler's waiting hook.

There is a convenient and comfortable myth to which many involved in Welsh politics cling, in which the electorate in Wales is of a radical disposition and finds the Tories toxic. Would that it were so; but whilst it may have been a couple of decades ago, it isn’t today. And the rise of Reform Ltd shows us that Tory toxicity isn’t about policies or personalities anyway, it’s just about branding. Take the same people and the same policies and give them a different brand name, and many voters will, apparently, flock to the cause. To a very large extent, I blame Labour for that. Firstly, because they’ve ceased to be particularly radical or even progressive, and secondly because they’ve depended for so long on one simple attribute rather than arguing for any particular policy platform: being 'not-the-Tories'. It turns out that even those who have voted for them for years, if not decades, have come to believe that Reform Ltd, despite being largely composed of ex-Tories, are also now ‘not-the-Tories’, with the additional advantage of being untainted (as a brand, even if not as individuals) by having failed in the exercise of power.

And that’s the point about the Green angler and his rod. Laying it down simply gives credence to, and reinforces, the idea that all self-identified ‘progressives’ essentially share a perspective, and that ‘progressive’ voters should support the ‘progressive’ candidate most likely to win. I doubt that the Green Party candidate will receive many votes in the by-election (sorry, Gareth), but even if the total votes cast for him is more than the difference between the first and second placed candidate, there will be no way of knowing that his absence would have made a difference – in a first-past-the-post election, his votes cannot simply be added mathematically to those of another candidate. And he will be putting a different perspective and agenda before the electorate – can giving the voters more choice ever be a bad thing?

There is actually a very good case for politicians to come to an agreement on which party will stand where, but it applies only to a single issue and is only relevant in a Westminster General Election. It relates to the question of electoral reform. A short, single issue parliament which passed such a law and then dissolved itself for a new election under new rules would be well worth while. The problem is that that single issue doesn’t neatly split itself between self-styled ‘progressives’ and ‘reactionaries’. And whether Farage will still be as keen on electoral reform if an election under FPTP gives him absolute power on a minority vote is an unanswered question. Not one to which I really want to discover the answer the hard way.

Thursday, 25 September 2025

Depending on character rather than formal rules could be even worse

 

Perhaps it was, as some around Trump like to believe, an act of deliberate sabotage when that escalator ground to a halt; perhaps it was an accident – an aide or a member of the press corps running on ahead and accidentally triggering the emergency stop. My own alternative theory is that Trump was feeling thirsty, saw a big red button, and thought that if he pressed it, someone would bring him a diet coke. Stupidity usually beats both accident and conspiracy.

Trump’s Press Secretary’s response to the incident was to say that “If someone at the U.N. intentionally stopped the escalator … they need to be fired and investigated immediately.” The order of events there is important: start with assumed guilt, implement the punishment, and then investigate to determine the facts. It’s very much a Queen of Hearts approach to justice. It’s certainly an approach that Trump has adopted elsewhere. He’s regularly declaring the guilt of people without having a shred of evidence, and demanding that they be punished immediately and then prosecuted. And if the prosecutors can’t find any evidence, then they should be fired and replaced with people who can. The evidence is probably hiding in the same place as those 11,780 votes that Trump demanded that Georgia’s Secretary of State should ‘find’ after he lost the 2020 election. When you ‘know’ that someone is guilty of breaking a law that you’ve just invented, it surely can’t be that hard to prove it.

The Queen of Hearts was, of course an absolute monarch. ‘Off with their heads’ was an instinctive response to just about anything. To date, the formal written constitution of the US has not proved to be the barrier which I had naively expected that it would be. Partly, that’s because Trump has managed to capture all three branches of government power; and partly because the US system of law grinds exceedingly slowly and no legal ruling ever seems to be final until an overwhelmed supreme court, tilted heavily in one political direction, eventually gets round to ruling. Maybe a written constitution doesn’t provide the protection that some of us might have imagined. On the other hand, just imagine how much more freedom a Trump might have in the UK where so many of the ’rules’ depend simply on precedent, the assumed good character of the incumbent, and the royal prerogative. The same applies, of course, to any Trump surrogate who might happen to come along.

Wednesday, 24 September 2025

What happens to migrants' property?

If Nigel Farage were ever to become UK Prime Minister and implement his policy of reversing the residency rights of just about anyone who had migrated to the UK in the past, what would happen to any assets which those migrants had accumulated? I mean, just supposing for a minute that you were a French politician who had found £885,000 down the back of the sofa to buy a house so that your boyfriend could claim to live somewhere that he rarely visited, what would happen to the house if you were forced to return to France so that your boyfriend could implement a wild promise he had made whilst campaigning?

Maybe Farage’s policy has some unstated loopholes, such as excluding French people in possession of valuable homes, although nothing he’s said so far implies any great willingness to make exceptions; he’s even ready to split families as part of his plan, so getting married and having kids doesn't work either. Maybe the assets of those expelled would simply pass to any convenient partner who was allowed to remain. That would make it quite a cunning plan – Farage would end up with a house in his constituency after all, and (unless he was the one who happened to lose £885,000 down the back of the sofa) he’d have got it for nothing.


Tuesday, 23 September 2025

Starmer and Reeves are feeding Farageism

 

Imagine for a moment a different world in which the UK managed to solve its endemic problems. It’s vanishingly unlikely, of course. As long as governments of whatever hue insist that the constraints on what they can do are a lack of money and the need to abide by a set of fiscal rules which they themselves have devised, rather than the availability of physical resources and the concentration of wealth in fewer and fewer hands, there is no real prospect of meaningful change.

But, for the sake of argument, bear with me for a moment. Suppose we could get to a situation where the NHS could provide the help that people need, when they need it, with negligible waiting lists; suppose that we had an educational system which produced consistently good results and was the envy of much of the world; suppose that everyone had adequate housing suitable to meet their needs. Suppose also that we had ‘full’ employment: in realistic terms, everyone of working age who was able to work could get a decently-paid job that they wanted to do; suppose that that included not just UK citizens, but also those who had come here from elsewhere; and suppose that all those who arrived from elsewhere spoke impeccable English (or Welsh, of course). In such an ideal world, do we believe that Farage, Badenoch, Starmer, Mahmoud etc. would stop banging on about the need to block migration and remove some or all of those already here?

Sadly, I don’t think it would change their position one iota. There are those who argue that they simply hate migrants per se – I don’t believe that they do. I suspect, rather more cynically, that they believe that a sufficient proportion of the electorate hate migrants so much that there are large numbers of votes to be had by being seen to be tough on migration. It’s not that the politicians themselves are racists or xenophobes, they’re simply willing to appeal to voters who are in order to win elections.

Whether their faith in the innate prejudices of a significant part of the electorate is justified or not is an unknown. For the reasons outlined at the beginning, it’s not a theory which is ever likely to be tested. And for as long as UK governments refuse to fix the problems which they can then blame on migrants, they will get away with pretending that anti-migrant feelings are based on what they choose to call ‘legitimate concerns’ rather than on prejudice and racism, and claim that expelling people rather then improving conditions is the way to solve those problems. Actually, it’s worse than that. By refusing to address the underlying problems and concentrating instead on deporting people, they reinforce the idea that migration is the source of the problems; in other words, the Reeves/Starmer fiscal rules reinforce the narrative about migration. Their ideological blinkers are directly aiding the Farages of this world.

Monday, 22 September 2025

How and why does something become a moral issue?

 

The UK’s Prime Minister has described his decision to recognise the state of Palestine as being a ‘moral responsibility’. It’s a nice rhetorical flourish to justify something which should have been done a long time ago, but it doesn’t explain how and why something which was apparently unacceptable to him last year suddenly became a moral imperative. Was it the non-stop killing of Gazans by Israel which tilted the balance? Maybe, but that doesn’t explain why so many had to die before it became a ‘moral’ issue. Perhaps it was the expansion of settlements in the West Bank and the driving out of Palestinians from the areas being settled, but that, too, has been going on for a long time. ‘Morality’ isn’t a numbers game; there’s no magic threshold at which deliberately killing civilians, including children, moves from being a practical issue to a moral one, no magic threshold at which the seizure of land becomes a moral issue. Framing it as a moral issue might sound good, but it also avoids serious action to bring about change.

The recognition is, in any event, more limited than it appears. No-one in their right mind would want to see Hamas forming the government of the newly-recognised state, but if the Palestinians have the right to a state (as Starmer argues), by what authority can the UK declare in advance that the people may not choose a government which includes a specified group or party? Although, on reflection, an international order which precludes certain individuals or groups from ever exercising power isn’t such a bad idea – there are a number of regimes across the world which I think we would be better off without. But who decides what is or is not acceptable, and how is it to be enforced? And if it is not a general rule, why should one ‘independent and sovereign state’ be singled out as uniquely having no right to choose whatever government it wishes? There are practical issues as well – banning an organisation is all well and good, but it’s easy enough for any organisation to disband and reform under another name.

There is one simple truth underlying what is happening in Palestine, and it applies to other conflicts as well. The world is not and never has been run on the basis of morality, and there isn’t even a single set of moral standards on which we all agree. It is actually run on the basis of raw power – in effect, ‘might is right’. He who possesses the power and armaments imposes his will on others. It’s a philosophy to which most of the world’s leaders (including Netanyahu, Trump, Putin, and, yes, Starmer himself) subscribe, in their actions if not in their words. As long as that remains true, those leaders talking of ‘moral responsibility’ is just window dressing.

Friday, 19 September 2025

Reinforcing migrant blame only keeps us on the same trajectory

 

As something of a parting shot yesterday, Trump told Starmer that immigration destroys countries from within, and advised him to deploy the military to stop migration. How that would work isn’t clear, but perhaps he means a few extra-judicial killings of the sort which he is implementing himself. Trumpland tends to see absolute destruction on all sides – his response to an unfavourable court ruling on his imposition of tariffs was to suggest that the court’s decision “would literally destroy the United States of America” as well. The threat of ‘absolute destruction’ is key to his regular invocation of an emergency of one sort or another. It’s hyperbole of course: a good general rule of thumb is that any sentence containing the word ‘literally’ is probably going to be more hyperbole than fact. Even when it isn’t from Trump.

I can’t think of any actual historical example which would lend support to the idea that immigration destroys countries; on the contrary, immigration has made many countries what they are today, with the US being perhaps the most obvious example. What immigration can do, however, is change the culture of a country, sometimes in small ways, and sometimes – especially when the ruling elite are drawn entirely from the immigrant population – much more drastically. Once again, the US stands out as a particular example of cultural replacement as Europeans marginalised, and at times massacred, the former population. The world’s greatest exponents of cultural replacement have been the European colonial powers, foremost amongst them Spain, England and France, but with dishonourable mentions for Portugal, Belgium, the Netherlands and Italy as well. And here in Wales, we are not exactly unfamiliar with the idea of cultural replacement either, albeit as victim more than perpetrator.

Does the current level of immigration – either into the US or the UK – really threaten that sort of cultural change? There’s no evidence to suggest that it does. Unlike a true invasion where the ruling group is replaced, attracting migrants into the general population really doesn’t have that much impact. Historical evidence says that, after two or three generations, the descendants of immigrants tend to absorb the majority culture more often than challenging or changing it. The economic impact of migration is disputed; most objective studies suggest that it has a net positive effect overall, but for those who are not being well-served by the economy at present, immigration is a convenient scapegoat. Especially when exaggerated by those who seek to use people’s fears and prejudices as a route to power. One of the main elements of those prejudices – we cannot avoid this truth – is a form of racism; not always based on skin colour, although that’s certainly a factor, but often on a fear or dislike of anyone seen to be ‘different’.

I seriously doubt whether the likes of Trump or Farage (or Starmer or Badenoch come to that) really care very much about immigration at all. Playing to perceived prejudices is just a route to power, and dividing those over whom they seek power is a bonus. The result is that, rather than challenging or changing those prejudices, they reinforce them. Those who seek to rebut the arguments generally highlight facts and statistics, but it’s an approach doomed to fail. People will not be swayed by facts and statistics from a view which was never based on facts or statistics in the first place. There is a certain inevitability about the destination if we stay on the current trajectory. A standard piece of advice to writers is ‘show, don’t tell’, and a good starting place for governing politicians would be to create and then demonstrate economic success for all rather than verbally reinforcing blame. I’m not holding my breath.