It’s more than 60
years since Parkinson came up with his famous law that "work expands so as to fill the time
available for its completion". I’m
not sure that it’s ever been scientifically ‘proven’, but for most of us it
seems to have a ring of truth about it in many workplaces, in offices at
least. The underlying problem that it
highlights is the difficulty in measuring the productivity of many activities. In essence, productivity is simply output
divided by input, and in a widget factory it’s fairly easy to measure both and
thus assess productivity – it’s simply the number of widgets produced divided
by person hours to produce them. (In
passing, it’s worth noting that that isn’t quite the way in which overall
productivity of the economy is calculated, but that’s for another day.)
In an office
environment, however, measuring ‘output’ is a great deal harder to do, which is
why many lazy employers don’t even try.
Instead, they put their efforts into managing the input side of the equation:
controlling the hours put in by employees, managing sickness absence, dealing
with a lack of punctuality. There’s an
underlying and unstated assumption that if they can maximise and control the
input then the output will take care of itself.
It’s an invalid assumption, and in some cases over-controlling the input
side of the equation leads to a disempowered, or even demotivated, workforce
which feels, rightly, that management don’t trust them to get on with the job;
and the probable impact of that on output (and thus productivity) is more
likely to be negative than positive.
That’s something
of the context within which the TUC this week called for a move towards
a four-day week rather than a five-day one.
The BBC report tells the story of one company which switched to four-day
working and found that they were achieving as much as they had before. From simple observation over the years, I
suspect that would be true of many workplaces.
‘Presenteeism’ is a growing problem, and the number of employees who
believe that they should be seen to turn up before the boss and not leave until
after (s)he has gone home is far too prevalent.
It leads to some people working long hours involving what is often
unpaid overtime, but I’m not at all convinced that it adds anything to output. Instead, the Pareto Principle
applies: staff achieve 80% of their overall impact in 20% of the available
time; the remaining 80% of their time is taken up by often trivial activities
having little overall impact.
Presenteeism merely adds to the time used for not particularly productive
activity.
It’s not clear
yet to what extent automation will replace much of the routine work undertaken
by staff in offices. Again, it’s easier
to see the impact of automation in a widget factory. I suspect, however, that most people are
underestimating the extent to which technology will be able to replace much of
the work currently done, as well as underestimating the rate at which that
change will be upon us. The TUC talk
about sharing the benefits of technology with the workforce; reducing the
length of the working week is one way of doing that. It strikes me, though, as a wholly inadequate
response to the impending changes which technology will bring. The challenge is not just about sharing the
benefits in the workplace, it’s about sharing those benefits more widely across
society. I suppose it’s close to
inevitable that an organisation composed of the representatives of working
people will be prioritising the interests of those working people; but there
are a lot of people in society who aren’t in that category who will also be affected. And that number is likely to grow.
Some politicians
talk about automation as though it’s similar to changes of the past, as a
result of which many jobs disappeared but were replaced by new jobs and new
types of jobs which hadn’t even been imagined previously. They may be right, and if they are I may be
worrying unduly. I have a feeling
however that the change we are now facing is of a different nature – even if
new types of organisation supplying new types of services emerge, the potential
is there for many of them to be automated too.
In theory, those who own the machines can produce goods and services with
little dependence on employees, and the benefits of automation accrue to the
machine owners.
Things aren’t
quite that simple, however, and the advance of technology highlights the
underlying problem with the capitalist economic model. For those organisations adopting the
technology first and moving away from dependence on human employees there are
potentially huge advantages. But if
everyone does it, and there are no employees left, who has the money to buy the
goods and services? What looks good for
an individual capitalist simply doesn’t work when applied to the economy as a
whole. That has always been the flaw in
the model but continued economic growth has disguised it. I paint an extreme picture to make a point,
but unchecked automation with all the benefits flowing to the automators
ultimately fails. The TUC are right to
argue that the benefits of automation should be shared more widely; if
anything, their proposals strike me as being rather timid. What they are suggesting is in the interests
of the capitalists as well as the workers, but I don’t expect the capitalists
to recognise that just yet. There is a
wider political question as well – what are politicians going to do to ensure
that the benefits are shared rather than accruing to one group alone in the
short term? Merely assuming that there
will be new jobs to replace the old looks is not just complacent - it’s more a
dereliction of duty.
No comments:
Post a Comment