There is a degree of poetic justice in the
way in which a proposal to commit the Labour Party to supporting electoral
reform was defeated
yesterday. The votes of ordinary members (allegedly) were overruled by block
votes cast by a handful of union bosses and leaders of other ‘affiliates’. It
gets better (or worse, depending on your viewpoint); since an ordinary member
can also be a member of a trade union and of one or more affiliated group, the
same member can vote three or more times. There must be many ‘members’ of the
Labour Party who ‘voted’ three times – probably once in favour and twice
against, looking at the numbers (available here) –
without ever having been asked for their opinion. A party which can operate its
own affairs under such a flawed system, and justify retaining such a system, is
not going to become a beacon for electoral reform.
This
article yesterday (by an obviously Labour-supporting academic) set
out some of the reasons for Labour’s persistent rejection of electoral reform. Ultimately,
it seems to come down to the view that FPTP suits the Labour Party, and that
there is no evidence that a system of PR would have made a Labour Government
more likely. And it amounts to an admission that, as previously noted, the
Labour Party would sooner allow the Tories to have absolute power for most of
the time in exchange for Labour having an occasional turn, using an electoral
system which encourages people to vote against the party they dislike most by
voting for the only other one which stands a realistic chance of forming a
government. The classic paragraph for me was this one:
“With the exception of the
remarkable 1945 election, the British public have never voted in a majority for
leftwing parties. Adding together the votes of Labour, the Greens, the SNP and
Plaid Cymru at every other general election has never amounted to more than 50%
of the vote. This is not to say that leftwing governments are impossible under
PR, but there is virtually no evidence from British election history that more
than 50% of British voters are prepared to vote for leftwing parties.”
It's an astonishing argument which amounts
to saying that, because we can’t persuade enough people to support a left-wing
programme (even supposing that we could call Labour’s programme ‘left-wing’,
which is a whole other argument), we need an electoral system which allows us
to impose such a programme based on a minority of votes. But is the underlying
assumption – that under PR people would have voted for the same parties at
every election as they did under FPTP – actually true? It seems to me unlikely; at the very least, freed of the pressure to choose between one of the ‘big two’
parties on the basis of which they hate least, and knowing that voting for
their first choice party could no longer be described as a ‘wasted vote’, it is
surely more likely that votes would be distributed rather differently. And that, in turn, might have had significant effects.
As an example of possible differences,
even under FPTP, UKIP gained around 12.5% of the votes in the 2015 General
Election. Had that been translated into seats, they would have held around 81
seats, a sizeable group in the Commons. And if people had believed that they
could win, their vote might well have been higher. Had that happened, would the
Conservative Party have fallen so heavily under the control of extreme
Brexiteers, or would those extremists have remained more isolated in another
parliamentary block? Would there even have been a referendum on the EU? Would
their vote have collapsed in the following elections in the way in which it
did? Engaging in ‘What If?’ is interesting, but ultimately a bit fruitless,
other than to support the contention that the assumption that people would have
voted the same way is unlikely to be valid.
The truth is that none of us can be
certain what previous election results would have looked like under PR. Nor can
we know what difference it will make to future election results. What we do
know, however, is:
1. It
would be more likely that people would feel able to vote for their first choice
party rather than vote for the party most likely to defeat the party they like
the least, and
2. The
distribution of seats in parliament would more closely match the distribution
of opinions amongst the electorate.
Arguing that securing a victory for ‘our’
party is more important than either of those outcomes is fundamentally undemocratic.
But that’s where Labour now finds itself.